Optimal Portfolio - Carole Bernard

materialized through S* - drops below its Value-at-Risk at some high confidence level. ..... An insight of this work is that if all institutional investors implement ...
5MB taille 3 téléchargements 309 vues
Optimal Portfolio Under Worst-Case Scenarios Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (UW) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Rennes, March 2012.

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

1/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Contributions 1

A better understanding of the link between Growth Optimal Portfolio and optimal investment strategies

2

Understanding issues with traditional diversification strategies and how lowest outcomes of optimal strategies always happen in the worse states of the economy.

3

Develop innovative strategies to cope with this observation.

4

Implications in terms of assessing the risk and return of a strategy and in terms of reducing systemic risk

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

2/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Part I:

Traditional Diversification Strategies

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

3/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) • The Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) maximizes expected

logarithmic utility from terminal wealth. • It has the property that it almost surely accumulates more

wealth than any other strictly positive portfolios after a sufficiently long time. • Under general assumptions on the market, the GOP is a

diversified portfolio. • Details in Platen (2006).

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

4/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) • The Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) maximizes expected

logarithmic utility from terminal wealth. • It has the property that it almost surely accumulates more

wealth than any other strictly positive portfolios after a sufficiently long time. • Under general assumptions on the market, the GOP is a

diversified portfolio. • Details in Platen (2006).

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

4/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

For example, in the Black-Scholes model • A Black-Scholes financial market (mainly for ease of

exposition) • Risk-free asset {Bt = B0 e rt , t > 0} •

  

dSt1 St1 dSt2 St2

= µ1 dt + σ1 dWt1 = µ2 dt + σ2 dWt

,

(1)

where W 1 and W are two correlated Brownian motions under the physical probability measure P. p Wt = ρWt1 + 1 − ρ2 Wt2 where W 1 and W 2 are independent. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

5/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Constant-Mix Strategy • Dynamic rebalancing to preserve the initial target allocation • The payoff of a constant-mix strategy is

Stπ = S0π exp(Xtπ ) where Xtπ is normal. • For an initial investment V0 , VT is given by

VT = V0

STπ , S0π

where π is the vector of proportions.

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

6/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Growth Optimal Portfolio (GOP) In the 2-dimensional Black-Scholes setting, • The GOP is a constant-mix strategy with  Xtπ = µπ − 12 σπ2 t + σπ Wtπ , that maximizes the expected growth rate µπ − 12 σπ2 . It is π ? = Σ−1 · (µ − r 1) .

(2)

• constant-mix portfolios given by π = απ ? with α > 0 and

where π ? is the optimal proportion for the GOP, are optimal strategies for CRRA expected utility maximizers. With a constant relative risk aversion coefficient η > 0, CRRA utility is ( 1−η x when η 6= 1 1−η U(x) = log(x) when η = 1, and α = 1/η. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

7/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Market Crisis The growth optimal portfolio S ? can also be interpreted as a major market index. Hence it is intuitive to define a stressed market (or crisis) at time T as an event where the market materialized through S ? - drops below its Value-at-Risk at some high confidence level. The corresponding states of the economy verify Crisis states = {ST? < qα } , (3) where qα is such that P(ST? < qα ) = 1 − α and α is typically high (e.g. α = 0.98).

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

8/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Srategy 1: GOP We invest fully in the GOP. In a crisis (GOP is low), our portfolio is low!

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

9/35

Strategy 1 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 200

180

Strategy 1

160

140

120

100

80

60 60

80

100 120 140 160 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ (T )

180

200

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Srategy 2: Buy-and-Hold The buy-and-hold strategy is the simplest investment strategy. An initial amount V0 is used to purchase w0 units of the bank account and wi units of stock S i (i = 1, 2) such that V0 = w0 + w1 S01 + w2 S02 , and no further action is undertaken. Example with 1/3 invested in each asset (bank, S1 and S2 ) on next slide.

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

11/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Srategy 2: Buy-and-Hold The buy-and-hold strategy is the simplest investment strategy. An initial amount V0 is used to purchase w0 units of the bank account and wi units of stock S i (i = 1, 2) such that V0 = w0 + w1 S01 + w2 S02 , and no further action is undertaken. Example with 1/3 invested in each asset (bank, S1 and S2 ) on next slide.

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

11/35

Strategy 2 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 220 200 180

Strategy 2

160 140 120 100 80 60 60

80

100 120 140 160 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ (T )

180

200

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Strategy 3: Constant-Mix Strategy Example with 1/3 invested in each asset (bank, S1 and S2 ).

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

13/35

Strategy 3 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 200

180

Strategy 3

160

140

120

100

80

60 60

80

100 120 140 160 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ (T )

180

200

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

I These three traditional diversification strategies do not offer protection during a crisis. I In a more general setting, optimal strategies share the same problem...

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

15/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Part II:

Optimal portfolio selection for law-invariant preferences

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

16/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Stochastic Discount Factor and Real-World Pricing: The GOP can be used as numeraire to price under P     XT Price of −rT = EQ [e XT ] = EP [ξT XT ] = EP XT at 0 ST? where S0? = 1.

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

17/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Stochastic Discount Factor and Real-World Pricing: The GOP can be used as numeraire to price under P     XT Price of −rT = EQ [e XT ] = EP [ξT XT ] = EP XT at 0 ST? where S0? = 1.

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

17/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Cost-efficient strategies (Dybvig (1988)) Optimal Portfolio Selection Problem: Consider an investor with fixed investment horizon: max U(XT ) XT

subject to a given “cost of XT ” (equal to initial wealth) • Law-invariant preferences XT ∼ YT ⇒ U(XT ) = U(YT ) • Increasing preferences XT ∼ F , YT ∼ G , ∀x, F (x) 6 G (x) ⇒ U(XT ) > U(YT ) A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. The optimal strategy for U must be cost-efficient. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

18/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Cost-efficient strategies (Dybvig (1988)) Optimal Portfolio Selection Problem: Consider an investor with fixed investment horizon: max U(XT ) XT

subject to a given “cost of XT ” (equal to initial wealth) • Law-invariant preferences XT ∼ YT ⇒ U(XT ) = U(YT ) • Increasing preferences XT ∼ F , YT ∼ G , ∀x, F (x) 6 G (x) ⇒ U(XT ) > U(YT ) A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. The optimal strategy for U must be cost-efficient. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

18/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Cost-efficient strategies (Dybvig (1988)) Optimal Portfolio Selection Problem: Consider an investor with fixed investment horizon: max U(XT ) XT

subject to a given “cost of XT ” (equal to initial wealth) • Law-invariant preferences XT ∼ YT ⇒ U(XT ) = U(YT ) • Increasing preferences XT ∼ F , YT ∼ G , ∀x, F (x) 6 G (x) ⇒ U(XT ) > U(YT ) A strategy (or a payoff) is cost-efficient if any other strategy that generates the same distribution under P costs at least as much. The optimal strategy for U must be cost-efficient. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

18/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Optimal Portfolio and Cost-efficiency Consider an investor with increasing law-invariant preferences and a fixed horizon. Denote by XT the investor’s final wealth. The optimal strategy solves a cost-efficiency problem   XT min E ST? {XT | XT ∼F } Reciprocally a cost-efficient strategy with a continuous distribution F corresponds to the optimum of an expected utility investor for Z x U(x) = G −1 (1 − F (y ))dy 0

where G is the cdf of Carole Bernard

1 ST? . Optimal Portfolio

19/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Optimal Portfolio and Cost-efficiency Consider an investor with increasing law-invariant preferences and a fixed horizon. Denote by XT the investor’s final wealth. The optimal strategy solves a cost-efficiency problem   XT min E ST? {XT | XT ∼F } Reciprocally a cost-efficient strategy with a continuous distribution F corresponds to the optimum of an expected utility investor for Z x U(x) = G −1 (1 − F (y ))dy 0

where G is the cdf of Carole Bernard

1 ST? . Optimal Portfolio

19/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Black-Scholes Model Theorem Consider the following optimization problem:   XT PD(F ) := min E ST? {XT | XT ∼F } In a Black-Scholes model, the optimal strategy (cheapest way to get F ) is   XT? = F −1 FST? (ST? ) . Note that XT? ∼ F and XT? is a.s. unique. Corollary A strategy with payoff XT = h(ST? ) is cost-efficient if and only if h is non-decreasing. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

20/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Black-Scholes Model Theorem Consider the following optimization problem:   XT PD(F ) := min E ST? {XT | XT ∼F } In a Black-Scholes model, the optimal strategy (cheapest way to get F ) is   XT? = F −1 FST? (ST? ) . Note that XT? ∼ F and XT? is a.s. unique. Corollary A strategy with payoff XT = h(ST? ) is cost-efficient if and only if h is non-decreasing. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

20/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Idea of the proof   XT min E XT ST? ( XT ∼ F subject to 1 S? ∼ G T

Recall that  corr XT ,

1 ST?

 =

i h E XT S1? − E[ S1? ]E[XT ] T

T

std( S1? ) std(XT )

.

T

We can prove that when the distributions for both XT and S1? are T fixed, we have   1 ? (XT , ST ) is comonotonic ⇒ corr XT , ? is minimal. ST Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

21/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Idea of the proof   XT min E XT ST? ( XT ∼ F subject to 1 S? ∼ G T

Recall that  corr XT ,

1 ST?

 =

i h E XT S1? − E[ S1? ]E[XT ] T

T

std( S1? ) std(XT )

.

T

We can prove that when the distributions for both XT and S1? are T fixed, we have   1 ? (XT , ST ) is comonotonic ⇒ corr XT , ? is minimal. ST Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

21/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Part III:

Investment under Worst-Case Scenarios

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

22/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Investment with State-Dependent Constraints Problem considered so far 

min

{XT | XT ∼F }

 XT E . ST?

A payoff that solves this problem is cost-efficient. New Problem 

min

{VT | VT ∼F , S}

 VT E . ST?

where S denotes a set of constraints. A payoff that solves this problem is called a S−constrained cost-efficient payoff.

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

23/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Type of Constraints We are able to find optimal strategies with final payoff VT I with an additional probability constraint P(ST? 6 s, VT 6 v ) = β I with a set of probability constraints ∀(s, v ) ∈ S, P(ST? 6 s, VT 6 v ) = Q(s, v ) where Q is an appropriate given function and S verifies some properties. I in particular, assuming that the final payoff of the strategy is independent of ST? during a crisis (defined as ST? 6 qα ), ∀s 6 qα , v ∈ R, P(ST? 6 s, VT 6 v ) = P(ST? 6 s)P(VT 6 v ) Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

24/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Independence in the Tail - Strategy 4: Path-dependent Theorem The cheapest path-dependent strategy with a cumulative distribution F but such that it is independent of ST? when ST? 6 qα can be constructed as    FS ? (ST? )−α  −1 T  F when ST? > qα ,  1−α            St? t ? ? VT =   ln S ? t/T −(1− T ) ln(S0 )  ( )     T −1  q F Φ    when ST? 6 qα ,  t2     σ t− ?  T   (4) where t ∈ (0, T ) can be chosen freely. (No uniqueness and path-independence anymore). Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

25/35

Strategy 4 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 200

180

Strategy 4

160

140

120

100

80

60 60

80

100 120 140 160 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ (T )

180

200

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Independence in the Tail - Strategy 5: Path-independent In a financial market that contains at least two assets that are continuously distributed, the cheapest path-independent strategy with a cumulative distribution F but such that it is independent of ST? when ST? 6 qα can be constructed as    ?  −1 FST? (ST )−α F when ST? > qα 1−α ZT? = . (5)  −1 ? F (Φ(A)) when ST 6 qα where A is explicitly known as a function of ST1 and ST? .

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

27/35

Strategy 5 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 200

180

Strategy 5

160

140

120

100

80

60 60

80

100 120 140 160 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ (T )

180

200

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Part IV:

Investment under Worst-Case Scenarios Some numerical examples

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

29/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Other Types of Dependence Recall that the joint cdf of a couple (ST? , X ) writes as P(ST? 6 s, XT 6 x) = C (H(s), F (x)) where • The marginal cdf of ST? : H • The marginal cdf of XT : F • A copula C Independence in the tail (independence copula C (u, v ) = uv ): ∀s 6 qα , v ∈ R, P(ST? 6 s, VT 6 v ) = P(ST? 6 s)P(VT 6 v ) I We were also able to derive formulas for optimal strategies that generate a Gaussian distribution in the tail with a correlation coefficient of -0.5. I Similarly for Clayton or Frank dependence. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

30/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Optimal Investment with a Clayton Tail Dependence

The cheapest strategy VT? with cdf F that verifies this Clayton dependence (with correlation -0.5) in the tail is  h i−1/a   −1 ? −a −a  F (FST? (ST ) − α) − (1 − α) + 1 if ST? > qα ? VT =      F −1 g 1 − FS ? (S ? ), jF ? (S ? ) (FZ (ZT )) if ST? 6 qα , T T S T T T

where ZT is such that (ST? , ZT ) is continuously distributed (with copula J) and where g is known explicitly: h   i−1/a g (u, v ) = u −a v −a/(1+a) − 1 + 1 .

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

31/35

Strategy 8 vs the Growth Optimal Portfolio 200

180

Strategy 8

160

140

120

100

80

60 60

80

100 120 140 160 Growth Optimal Portfolio, S ∗ (T )

180

200

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Some numerical results We define two events related to the market, i.e. the market crisis ? C = {S and  T? < qα?} rT a decrease in the market D = ST < S0 e . We further define two events for the portfolio value by A = VT < V0 e rT and B = VT < 75%V0 e rT

GOP Buy-and-Hold Independence Gaussian Clayton

Carole Bernard

T 5 5 5 5 5

Cost 100 100 101.67 103.40 102.35

Sharpe 0.266 0.239 0.214 0.159 0.193

P(A|C) 1.00 0.9998 0.46 0.12 0.24

P(A|D) 1.00 0.965 0.94 0.90 0.91

P(B|C) 1.00 0.99 0.13 0.01 0.02

Optimal Portfolio

33/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Conclusions • Cost-efficiency: a preference-free framework for ranking

different investment strategies. • Characterization of optimal portfolio strategies for

investors with law invariant preferences and a fixed horizon. I Lowest outcomes in worst states of the economy • Optimal investment choice under state-dependent

constraints.

• not always non-decreasing with the GOP ST? . • not anymore unique • could be path-dependent.

I Trade-off between losing “utility” and gaining from better fit of the investor’s preferences. Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

34/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

More Implications I The new strategies do not incur their biggest losses in the worst states in the economy. I can be used to reduce systemic risk. • the idea of assessing risk and performance of a portfolio not

only by looking at its final distribution but also by looking at its interaction with the economic conditions is indeed related to the increasing concern to evaluate systemic risk. • Acharya (2009) explains that regulators should “be regulating each bank as a function of both its joint (correlated) risk with other banks as well as its individual (bank-specific) risk”. • An insight of this work is that if all institutional investors implement strategies that are resilient against crisis regimes, as we propose, then systemic risk can be diminished.

Do not hesitate to contact me to get updated working papers! Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

35/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

References I Bernard, C., Boyle P., Vanduffel S., 2011, “Explicit Representation of Cost-efficient Strategies”, available on SSRN. I Bernard, C., Jiang, X., Vanduffel, S., 2012. “Note on Improved Frechet bounds and model-free pricing of multi-asset options”, Journal of Applied Probability. I Bernard, C., Maj, M., Vanduffel, S., 2011. “Improving the Design of Financial Products in a Multidimensional Black-Scholes Market,”, North American Actuarial Journal. I Bernard, C., Vanduffel, S., 2011. “Optimal Investment under Probability Constraints,” AfMath Proceedings. I Bernard, C., Vanduffel, S., 2012. “Financial Bounds for Insurance Prices,”Journal of Risk Insurance. I Cox, J.C., Leland, H., 1982. “On Dynamic Investment Strategies,” Proceedings of the seminar on the Analysis of Security Prices,(published in 2000 in JEDC). I Dybvig, P., 1988a. “Distributional Analysis of Portfolio Choice,” Journal of Business. I Dybvig, P., 1988b. “Inefficient Dynamic Portfolio Strategies or How to Throw Away a Million Dollars in the Stock Market,” Review of Financial Studies. I Goldstein, D.G., Johnson, E.J., Sharpe, W.F., 2008. “Choosing Outcomes versus Choosing Products: Consumer-focused Retirement Investment Advice,” Journal of Consumer Research. I Jin, H., Zhou, X.Y., 2008. “Behavioral Portfolio Selection in Continuous Time,” Mathematical Finance. I Nelsen, R., 2006. “An Introduction to Copulas”, Second edition, Springer. I Pelsser, A., Vorst, T., 1996. “Transaction Costs and Efficiency of Portfolio Strategies,” European Journal of Operational Research. I Platen, E., 2005. “A benchmark approach to quantitative finance,” Springer finance. I Tankov, P., 2011. “Improved Frechet bounds and model-free pricing of multi-asset options,” Journal of Applied Probability, forthcoming. I Vanduffel, S., Chernih, A., Maj, M., Schoutens, W. 2009. “On the Suboptimality of Path-dependent Pay-offs in L´ evy markets”, Applied Mathematical Finance.

∼∼∼ Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

36/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Part V:

Proofs with Copulas Optimal Portfolio under Tail Dependence

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

37/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Copulas and Sklar’s theorem The joint cdf of a couple (ξT , X ) can be decomposed into 3 elements • The marginal cdf of ξT : G • The marginal cdf of XT : F • A copula C

such that P(ξT 6 ξ, XT 6 x) = C (G (ξ), F (x))

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

38/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Where do copulas appear?

in the derivation of “cost-efficient” strategies...

Solving the cost-efficiency problem amounts to finding bounds on copulas! min E [ξT XT ] XT  XT ∼ F subject to ξT ∼ G

Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

39/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Proof of the cost-efficient payoff min E [ξT XT ] XT  XT ∼ F subject to ξT ∼ G The distribution G is known and depends on the financial market. Let C denote a copula for (ξT , X ). Z Z E[ξT X ] =

(1 − G (ξ) − F (x) + C (G (ξ), F (x)))dxdξ,

(6)

The lower bound for E[ξT X ] is derived from the lower bound on C max(u + v − 1, 0) 6 C (u, v ) (where max(u + v − 1, 0) corresponds to the anti-monotonic copula). E [ξ F −1 (1 − G (ξ ))] 6 E [ξ X ] T

T

T

T

then XT? = F −1 (1 − G (ξT )) has the minimum price for the cdf F . Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

40/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Proof of the cost-efficient payoff min E [ξT XT ] XT  XT ∼ F subject to ξT ∼ G The distribution G is known and depends on the financial market. Let C denote a copula for (ξT , X ). Z Z E[ξT X ] =

(1 − G (ξ) − F (x) + C (G (ξ), F (x)))dxdξ,

(6)

The lower bound for E[ξT X ] is derived from the lower bound on C max(u + v − 1, 0) 6 C (u, v ) (where max(u + v − 1, 0) corresponds to the anti-monotonic copula). E [ξ F −1 (1 − G (ξ ))] 6 E [ξ X ] T

T

T

T

then XT? = F −1 (1 − G (ξT )) has the minimum price for the cdf F . Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

40/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Proof of the cost-efficient payoff min E [ξT XT ] XT  XT ∼ F subject to ξT ∼ G The distribution G is known and depends on the financial market. Let C denote a copula for (ξT , X ). Z Z E[ξT X ] =

(1 − G (ξ) − F (x) + C (G (ξ), F (x)))dxdξ,

(6)

The lower bound for E[ξT X ] is derived from the lower bound on C max(u + v − 1, 0) 6 C (u, v ) (where max(u + v − 1, 0) corresponds to the anti-monotonic copula). E [ξ F −1 (1 − G (ξ ))] 6 E [ξ X ] T

T

T

T

then XT? = F −1 (1 − G (ξT )) has the minimum price for the cdf F . Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

40/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Sufficient condition for the existence Theorem Let t ∈ (0, T ). If there exists a copula L satisfying S such that L 6 C (pointwise) for all other copulas C satisfying S then the payoff YT? given by YT? = F −1 (f (ξT , ξt )) is a S-constrained cost-efficient payoff. Here f (ξT , ξt ) is given by f (ξT , ξt ) = `G (ξT )

−1 

 jG (ξT ) (G (ξt )) ,

where the functions ju (v ) and `u (v ) are defined as the first partial derivative for (u, v ) → J(u, v ) and (u, v ) → L(u, v ) respectively and where J denotes the copula for the random pair (ξT , ξt ). If (U, V ) has a copula L then `u (v ) = P(V 6 v |U = u). When S = ∅, f (ξt , ξT ) = F −1 (1 − G (ξT )). Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

41/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Sufficient condition for the existence Theorem Let t ∈ (0, T ). If there exists a copula L satisfying S such that L 6 C (pointwise) for all other copulas C satisfying S then the payoff YT? given by YT? = F −1 (f (ξT , ξt )) is a S-constrained cost-efficient payoff. Here f (ξT , ξt ) is given by f (ξT , ξt ) = `G (ξT )

−1 

 jG (ξT ) (G (ξt )) ,

where the functions ju (v ) and `u (v ) are defined as the first partial derivative for (u, v ) → J(u, v ) and (u, v ) → L(u, v ) respectively and where J denotes the copula for the random pair (ξT , ξt ). If (U, V ) has a copula L then `u (v ) = P(V 6 v |U = u). When S = ∅, f (ξt , ξT ) = F −1 (1 − G (ξT )). Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

41/35

Introduction

Diversification Strategies

Cost-Efficiency

Tail Dependence

Numerical Example

Conclusions

Proofs

Existence of the optimum ⇔ Existence of minimum copula Theorem (Sufficient condition for existence of a minimal copula L) Let S be a rectangle [u1 , u2 ] × [v1 , v2 ] ⊆ [0, 1]2 . Then a minimal copula L(u, v ) satisfying S exists and is given by L(u, v ) = max {0, u + v − 1, K (u, v )} . where K (u, v ) = max(a,b)∈ S {Q(a, b) − (a − u)+ − (b − v )+ }. Proof in a note written with Xiao Jiang and Steven Vanduffel extending Tankov’s result. Consequently the existence of a S−constrained cost-efficient payoff is guaranteed when S is a rectangle. More generally it also holds when S ⊆ [0, 1]2 satisfies a “monotonicity property” of the upper and lower “boundaries” and   v0 + v1 ∀ (u, v0 ) , (u, v1 ) ∈ S, u, ∈ S. (7) 2 Carole Bernard

Optimal Portfolio

42/35